Continue reading this on our app for a better experience

Open in App
Floating Button
Home Views Buybacks

Biden's misguided tax on share buybacks

Theo Vermaelen
Theo Vermaelen  • 4 min read
Biden's misguided tax on share buybacks
Photo by Wance Paleri on Unsplash
Font Resizer
Share to Whatsapp
Share to Facebook
Share to LinkedIn
Scroll to top
Follow us on Facebook and join our Telegram channel for the latest updates.

A 1% tax on companies purchasing their own shares from the market was signed into law by US President Joe Biden on Aug 16, as part of a bill addressing climate change and healthcare. Initial market reaction to the tax, expected to raise US$74 billion ($103.2 billion) over nine years, was muted, as were the predictions by analysts on the impact on corporate behaviour.

Indeed, a 1% tax is too trivial to make firms change their payout policy. The new tax will not change corporate behaviour and will ultimately make matters worse. The levy on share buybacks was apparently introduced to secure Arizona Senator Kyrsten Sinema’s support. Sinema had insisted on dropping planned tax increases on manufacturers and the private equity industry. The buyback tax is supposed to make up for the lost tax revenue. It may, however, just be the start of more to come, leading Democratic lawmaker Chuck Schumer indicated earlier this month.

“I hate stock buybacks,” Schumer reportedly said. “Instead of investing in workers, training and research, or equipment, they don’t do a thing to make the company better and they artificially raise the stock price by just reducing the number of shares. They are despicable. I’d like to abolish them”.

Schumer’s accusation that buybacks come at the expense of capital investment assumes that firms have no excess cash or debt capacity, or that they cannot issue equity later. Firms have excess cash when they have more money than they need to invest in good projects, namely projects with a positive net present value (NPV). What Schumer advocates is tantamount to making firms invest in bad projects that benefit other stakeholders at the expense of shareholders.

Optimal capital allocation should mean that firms with excess cash pay it out to shareholders. These shareholders can then give the money to firms that need capital for positive NPV projects. Discouraging firms from paying out excess cash may therefore lead to overall lower investment, the opposite of the intention of the tax.

Buybacks are not a manipulation scheme

See also: Re Re Create New Article 1 minute ago

Moreover, why pick on buybacks and not criticise dividends? Companies are reluctant to cut dividends, so a dividend increase is a much longer and stronger commitment to pay out cash than a buyback. Repurchase authorisations are options to repurchase stock, not a firm commitment. If a company runs into a great project, it will simply not complete the buyback.

Schumer’s argument that buybacks artificially increase stock prices because they reduce the number of shares ignores the fact that companies have to spend cash to buy back the shares. As long as the company buys the stock at fair value, nothing should happen to the stock price.

Although earnings per share may increase if the return on assets is higher than the return on cash used to buy back stock, the earnings are now riskier and should therefore be discounted at a higher rate. The present value of earnings per share does not increase. Again, there is no reason why a buyback should automatically increase stock prices.

See also: NoonTalk to seek approval at EGM for share purchase mandate

Nevertheless, there is a lot of empirical evidence that buyback authorisation announcements indeed increase stock prices. The most obvious explanation is that investors see the buyback as a signal that the stock is undervalued and that the management is confident about the future. They may also see the fact that excess cash is paid out rather than wasted in negative NPV projects as an indication of a commitment to shareholder value and hence, good corporate governance.

But if buybacks were a manipulation scheme, stock prices should rise at the time of the announcement and fall back to the pre-announcement level, as the actual repurchase takes place at a higher price after the announcement. The empirical evidence shows just the opposite: Stock prices increase abnormally afterwards, to the extent that executives who sell the stock after a buyback announcement are worse off than long-term investors.

In short, the hatred of buybacks expressed by the leader of the Democratic Party can only be explained by unfamiliarity with finance theory and evidence, and/or by ideological aversion to maximising shareholder value.

Theo Vermaelen is a professor of finance at INSEAD and the UBS chair in investment banking, endowed in honour of Henry Grunfeld

Highlights

Re test Testing QA Spotlight
1000th issue

Re test Testing QA Spotlight

×
The Edge Singapore
Download The Edge Singapore App
Google playApple store play
Keep updated
Follow our social media
© 2024 The Edge Publishing Pte Ltd. All rights reserved.